May the pro-poor impacts of trade liberalisation vanish because of imperfect information?☆
Introduction
The global welfare impact of trade liberalisation, including the agricultural sector (Hertel et al., 1999, Hertel and Martin, 2000, Anderson, 2002) stands at the forefront of trade economist's pre-occupations. The development of a generic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model (Hertel, 1997) and large expected spill-overs between economic sectors have generated numbers of studies based on this methodology. These underline the positive effect of trade liberalisation due to efficiency gains. Yet, a growing concern about the impacts of trade liberalisation in developing countries, especially on poverty, has arisen. The consequences of various liberalisation scenarios are now under scrutiny from the viewpoint of equity within these countries (Hertel et al., 2002).
The new round of negotiations has been called the development round, in the hope, among other reasons, that trade liberalisation will help in fighting poverty. However, a particular bottleneck may arise from price instability. The negative impacts of price instability on the poorest are well documented. As consumers, they often spend more than half of their expenditures on food, which makes them sensitive to any price increase. With price instability and risk averse producers, supply is reduced at mean price equivalent. Thus, price instability increases mean prices, harming the poor.
Indeed, since the Roosevelt era, in the 1930's, following this simple reasoning, governments have tried to isolate their markets from world food price fluctuations through trade policies. Recently, stabilisation has been recommended to fight poverty, on the ground that risk limits producer's investments and prevents them—especially, the poorest—using more efficient technology (Timmer, 2000). In this context, attempts have been made to include price instability and its impact on the poorest in trade liberalisation analysis (Hertel et al., 2001). But how can such instability be accounted for in models, which by construction assume that prices are perfectly known? The key underlying issue, here, is where instability comes from.
Most of the time, price instability is only considered as a consequence of external shocks like climatic disturbances. In such a case, as demonstrated by Bale and Lutz (1979) and evaluated by Tyer and Anderson (1992), removing trade barriers stabilises world price, because of the ‘Law of large numbers’: many independent small shocks in various directions cancel out when pooled in one large market. Thus, including price instability in the model should improve the pro-poor impacts of trade liberalisation (Hertel et al., 2001).
However, random events may not possess the nice properties of ‘Gaussian’ perturbations (Mandelbrot, 1971). Moreover, weather and other ‘small’ random events are not the only sources of price instability (Roll, 1984). A part, at least, of price instability in commodity markets is due to market behaviour itself. Such a situation arises with imperfect information (Kindleberger, 1996, Chavas and Holt, 1991). Ezekiel (1938) stressed the importance of price expectations in the price formation process. He showed that markets may tend to fail if demand is rigid and supply elastic, with huge fluctuations, panics and crashes. Several later authors, in the tradition of business cycle analysis, have shown that endogenous price fluctuations may be generated by models including liquidity constraint, risk and relatively rigid demand curves (Boussard, 1996, Day, 1999, Rosser, 2000).
When the source of fluctuations is non-Gaussian random events, or deterministic chaotic disturbances, conclusions derived from standard insurance analysis are no longer valid. For that reason, Stiglitz (2000) reminds us that the market economy is subject to large fluctuations and that public regulations are required, as demonstrated by the recurrent currency crisis in the 1990s. In this paper, imperfect information and expectations are introduced into a standard CGE model that includes a rich and a poor household in each region. Results from two versions of the model (that is, the standard model versus the model with imperfect information assumptions) are analysed and compared.
Section snippets
Modifying the basic CGE
Let us define the sets I for factors, J for commodities, H for institutions, t for time. Denote by: Fj(·), a production function; Uht(·), the utility function of consumer h; and G(·), the investment function, which transforms inputs into factors—mainly capital, but manpower as well.
Call yjt, the supply of commodity j; zhjt, the final consumption of commodity j by consumer h; xij, the quantity of commodity or factor i used as input for commodity j; vkjt, the demand of commodity j by consumer k
A world of perfect foresight versus uncertainty: models presentation
The GTAP database (version 4) has been used to represent the world through three2 regions (Europe, United States and Rest of the World), five production factors (land, natural resources, skilled
Results: welfare gains for the poor vanish with imperfect information
From a computational point of view, a difficulty with the version 2 specifications is that the model did not converge in every situation but sometimes ran over a large number of ‘years’ (we had results over 60 years), and sometimes failed to find a feasible solution after two years. The nature and parameter values of the expectation terms seemed to be important here, although it was difficult to discover generalities on the number of observations specific versions of the model could generate.
Conclusions
In this paper, two different versions of a world CGE model, one with classical perfect foresight, the other with imperfect information, are used to evaluate the impact of trade liberalisation on growth and poverty. For each version, the results of a ‘free-trade’ simulation are compared with the baseline scenario. The main finding is that the global gains associated with trade liberalisation are removed when imperfect information assumptions are introduced in the model. As underlined by Stiglitz
References (25)
When risk generates chaos
J. Econ. Behav. Organ.
(1996)Capital market liberalisation, economic growth, and instability
World Dev.
(2000)Agriculture, developing countries and the WTO
The Capital Myth
Foreign Aff., May/June
(1998)- et al.
The effect of trade intervention on international price instability
Am. J. Agric. Econ.
(1979) - Boussard, J.M., Gerard, F., Piketty, M.G., Christensen, A.K., Fallot, A., Voituriez, T, 2002. Modèle macro-économique à...
- Burniaux, J.-M., Van der Mensbrugghe, D., 1991. Trade policy in a global context: technical specification of the...
- et al.
On nonlinear dynamics: the case of the pork cycle
Am. J. Agric. Econ.
(August 1991) Complex Economic Dynamic volume II: An Introduction to Macroeconomic Dynamics
(1999)The world food markets: commodity risk management policy
Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ.
(1997)
The cobweb theorem
Q. J. Econ.
(1938)
Global Trade Analysis
(1997)
Cited by (10)
Dynamic modelling of agricultural policies: The role of expectation schemes
2011, Economic ModellingCitation Excerpt :On the other hand, we assume throughout our paper that economic agents are risk neutral in order to simplify the analysis. Boussard et al. (2004, 2006) specify the behaviour of risk averse farmers in a static way. They thus implicitly neglect the various dynamic decisions these agents have in order to deal with risks while recent econometric estimates show that these decisions critically influence the measure of this risk aversion (Pope et al., 2011).
Endogenous risk and long run effects of liberalization in a global analysis framework
2006, Economic ModellingThe effects of direct storage subsidies under limited rationality: A general equilibrium analysis
2015, Agricultural Economics (United Kingdom)Stabilisation policies in developing countries after the 2007-08 food crisis
2012, Agricultural Policies For Poverty ReductionInformal barriers and agricultural trade: Does monetary integration matter?
2011, Agricultural EconomicsAssessing agricultural trade policies options with the European Union: A Brazilian perspective
2009, Agricultural Economics
- ☆
- This paper is based on research partially funded by the French Ministry of Agriculture and Pluriagri. The views expressed here are the sole responsibility of authors, and do not necessarily reflect those of the funding organizations.
Copyright © 2004 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.